yego.me
💡 Stop wasting time. Read Youtube instead of watch. Download Chrome Extension

Shutting down or exiting industry based on price | APⓇ Microeconomics | Khan Academy


5m read
·Nov 11, 2024

We've spent several videos already talking about graphs like you see here. This is the graph for a particular firm; maybe it's making donuts, so it's in the donut industry. We can see how the marginal cost relates to the average variable cost and average total cost. We go into some depth several videos ago, but we see that trend: that marginal costs can trend down initially because as quantity increases, each incremental unit could benefit from things like specialization. Then the marginal cost, the cost of each incremental unit as a function of quantity, could go up because of things like coordination costs.

We've also seen how that relates to average variable costs: that while marginal cost is below average variable cost, every incremental unit is going to bring down the average variable cost. However, when marginal cost crosses average variable cost, now every incremental unit is going to bring up the average variable cost. The same thing happens once it crosses the average total cost. Of course, the difference, for any given quantity, between the average total cost and the average variable cost is the average fixed cost.

Now, with that out of the way, we're going to think about how this firm would react under different market conditions. We're going to assume that it's in a very competitive, or we could say a perfectly competitive, market. It is a price taker. Let's first imagine what would be a positive scenario for this firm. Let's imagine the price up here; so let's call this p sub 1. In a previous video, we already said it would be rational for a profit-maximizing firm to produce at a quantity where the marginal cost and the marginal revenue meet. In a competitive market, this price right over here is not going to be a function of the firm's quantity; that's why it's horizontal.

It would be the same thing as the marginal revenue. So in this situation, at p sub 1, the firm would produce q sub 1. This is a good situation for the firm because the price that it's getting is higher than its average total cost. There is going to be a nice amount of profit for this firm. The profit is going to be the price minus the average total cost at that quantity, times the actual quantity.

Because p1 is greater than the average total cost, we have a situation where the firm is profitable. It would want to stay in the market, but because you have a profitable firm in this market, you're likely to have many profitable firms in that market. It will probably attract entrants—other people might say, "Hey, I want to make just as much money as this donut company right over here." So you'll probably have more and more entrants into the market, which will probably reduce the prices.

They could reduce the prices until you get to a price that looks something like this. I will call that p sub 2. Now, a profit-maximizing firm in this world would keep producing until the marginal cost is equal to the marginal revenue, which in this case is the price. This would be my lines; they aren't completely straight, but you get the idea. So that's q sub 2. In this situation, p sub 2 is equal to the average total cost, so the firm is break-even. It's not running at a loss or a profit; it is break-even.

Here, the firm is neutral about whether, in the long run, it stays in the market or it exits the market. However, you're no longer likely to be attracting entrants. It does make sense for the firm to keep operating at this situation, even in the long run, because it is at least break-even.

Now let's imagine another scenario. Let's imagine this price level. For whatever reason, the market price gets to that. As we've talked about, a rational firm would be producing at q sub 3 and at p sub 3 right over here. There are some interesting things because p sub 3 is less than your average total cost; your firm is running at a loss—it's running at a loss here. So the firm is not profitable.

You might say, "Well, what is this firm likely to do? Would it just shut down?" Well, in the short run, it would not make sense for this firm to shut down because the price that it's getting is still higher than its average variable cost. In the short run, the fixed costs they've already been spent, so you might as well get as much incremental profit on the margin as you can. As long as the price is higher than the average variable cost, outside of their fixed cost, they're still making some money to make up those fixed costs.

So, you have two things going on: they would stay operating in the short run. But what would this firm do in the long run? In the long run, it makes no sense to be in a market where you can't make a profit. So, in the long run, it will exit. In general, the terminology when people are talking about whether to start or stop in the short run usually refers to whether you either shut down or operate.

In the long run, it's about exiting or entering the industry; for example, "Are you going to sell your factories or somehow dismantle them, or are you going to build new factories?" Of course, you have another even worse scenario for this firm, which might be down here where you have price sub 4. Here, in theory, this is where we intersect the marginal cost curve, q sub 4.

Now, here, it makes no sense for the company to operate at all because p sub 4 is less than the average total cost. You would want to exit in the long run, exit in the long run, exit the market. But you wouldn't even wait that long to sell your factories because p sub 4 is less than your average variable cost. You would also just shut down in the short run.

So, from a firm's point of view, you obviously want to be at p1, where you make a profit. But you might attract entrants at p sub 2. As a firm in the long run, you are neutral about exiting the market or entering the market or other people entering the market; you're at break-even at p sub 3. In the long run, you'd want to exit because you're not profitable. If the prices stay at p sub 3, your price is below your average total cost at the rational quantity to produce.

So, in the long run, you would exit. However, because p sub 3 is greater than your average variable cost at the rational quantity, you would stay operating in the short run. The last scenario, of course, is p sub 4, where the price gets so low that it just doesn't make sense to even operate another moment.

More Articles

View All
How One Line in the Oldest Math Text Hinted at Hidden Universes
(dramatic music) - [Derek] A single sentence in one of the oldest math books held the key to understanding our universe. Euclid’s “Elements” has been published in more editions than any other book except the Bible. It was the go-to math text for over 2,00…
We fund smart founders, irrespective of what they want to work on.
What’s the percentage of companies you’ve backed right now that have large language models? I think for Summer ‘23 it was close to 50% of the batch. And it’s pretty interesting! Like, I think a lot of people see that number and they think, “Oh, YC must h…
Plastics 101 | National Geographic
(bright music) [Narrator] Plastics have become such an entrenched part of our lives, but what exactly is plastic and how was it made? Before plastic became so ubiquitous, it underwent a transformation from being a strictly natural product to being synthe…
Climbing Asia’s Forgotten Mountain, Part 1 | Nat Geo Live
It was harder than we anticipated and it was much, much colder. We’re a team of six people. Our goal is to determine what the highest peak in Burma is and then climb it. Like to solve this fantastic geographical mystery. It never let up, just taken down t…
Center of mass equation | Impacts and linear momentum | Physics | Khan Academy
So let’s say you wanted to know where the center of mass was between this 2-kilogram mass and the 6-kilogram mass. Now, they’re separated by 10 centimeters, so it’s somewhere in between them, and we know it’s going to be closer to the larger mass because …
Spectrophotometry and the Beer–Lambert Law | AP Chemistry | Khan Academy
What I want to do in this video is to talk a little bit about spectrophotometry, spectrophotometry, photometry, which sounds fairly sophisticated, but it’s really based on a fairly simple principle. So if I have, let’s say we have two solutions that cont…