yego.me
💡 Stop wasting time. Read Youtube instead of watch. Download Chrome Extension

Lee Smolin: Physics Envy and Economic Theory


4m read
·Nov 4, 2024

So I got pulled into economics in 2007 because of the 2008 economic crisis. Mike Brown, who had been the first CFO of Microsoft, Chief Financial Officer of Microsoft and treasurer of Microsoft, he came to Toronto in 2007 and took my wife and I out to dinner and said he was trying to put together a research group to work on economics, and he would like me to be involved.

And I said, "I don't know anything about economics." And he said, "That's okay because nobody does and the whole system is about to collapse." He said, "The balance sheets of all the big investment banks -- it's like they have cancer. They're full of holes." And I remember being very struck by this because this was before anybody was talking about this.

And so I started to meet with a group of people that he was pulling together to understand what was gonna happen and to understand if there was any way to save the situation. It was a very ambitious thing and, of course, we failed. But along the way, I was motivated as a kind of public service to get interested in economics.

And what I found... economics, in a way, is very easy for a physicist to understand because it's very mathematical. And the mathematical models that they use are very clean. They're based on assumptions and hypotheses, and you can study them.

And as I studied it, I began to understand, some for myself and more from just reading around because the faults with the standard economic models, with the standard models of finance, are well known. They have been in the literature for decades and decades. So let me give some examples. The standard model of economics is called the neoclassical model and it assumes that markets or systems where trading happens between consumers and firms and there's certain simple models of how that goes on.

And the ideas that these come to equilibrium. Equilibrium, not in the physical sense, but in special economic sense in which you reach a point at which the prices are fixed such that market forces fix the prices such that you maximize the happiness of the consumers and maximize the profits of the firms.

And in so-called equilibrium, nobody can become happier or more profitable without somebody else becoming less happy or less profitable. And the ideology behind this -- not behind the mathematics because mathematics doesn't have an ideology -- but behind the arguments that were made and still are made from this model is that markets don't need regulation because they have these natural equilibria where everybody benefits to the maximum possible.

And if you're in equilibrium, you can't do better. Now there's a fault with this, and it's an obvious fault, and it's been known since the 1970s from some theorems proved by some economists including some of the founders of this field of mathematical economics, which is that there's not one equilibrium, there are many equilibria.

In fact, there's a vast number of equilibria. And so which equilibria, even assuming that this is a decent model of the economy which is not clear, but even assuming it's a good model, which equilibria you're in depends on the past history, it depends on regulation, it depends on politics, it depends on taste, it depends on changing taste, changing preferences.

And so history matters and what's called path dependence matters. This takes us outside the neoclassical model of economics but it doesn't take us outside of economics because some wiser economist, for example, Brian Arthur, had for years been developing models and theories of path dependent economy where the history does matter.

People from the area of complex systems like Stu Kauffman, Prubac in developing models of markets where the history matters, where there's not a single equilibrium, where there are many equilibria. And where change is paramount.

Another symptom of this is the idea that arbitrage isn't, I mean, in these neoclassical models when you go to equilibrium, arbitrage is impossible. Arbitrage is making a profit from trading around a circle of goods or a circle of currencies without actually producing anything.

And in equilibrium that's supposed to be impossible, but lots of firms and investment banks made fortunes off of currency trading, so why is that? It turns out because you're never really at equilibrium.

So why is the notion of equilibrium so powerful? I think part of the answer is this idea of physics envy, that economists thought that what they're doing was more scientific, hence more correct, if it looked like physics. And physics had this timeless picture in which what really mattered, as we were saying before, is the whole history of the system.

And in physics there's also a big notion of coming to equilibrium which is, although, however, it's important to say, a different notion of equilibrium. And somehow people in economics got seduced into this model which again works in the small -- if you have a small little corner of the economy, a small market -- it may work for a while to characterize approximately what's going on.

Arbitrage is not always there. It's not always, I mean, arbitrage, arbitrage does get eaten up. There are market forces which do push you towards equilibria. There's some truth in it. But the whole thing is a disaster if I can say that as an outsider.

And it led indirectly -- it wasn't the only reason why regulations were lifted on markets and trading through the decades, but when people were making arguments to Congress, to the President's office that the economy would be better off without regulation, this was the "scientific rationale for it" and led to the very unstable situation of the last economic crisis.

And indeed there's still a very dangerous and unstable situation in the world economy because -- well, I'm not an economist. I'm not gonna pontificate about the problems in the economy, but one could see how the idea of timelessness gave false comfort to an unsuccessful scientific theory in the realm of economics.

More Articles

View All
The Middle colonies | Period 2: 1607-1754 | AP US History | Khan Academy
Over the course of the 1600s, the English continued to settle along the eastern seaboard of North America. Now, we’ve already talked about the settlements at Virginia and those of Massachusetts, and a little bit about the settlement of New York, which was…
The Art of Receiving Feedback | Big Think
So the ability to turn down feedback and create boundaries is crucial to receiving feedback well and really to creating healthy relationships. One of the paradoxes of receiving feedback well is that in order to be able to say yes, you also have to be able…
How architecture helped music evolve - David Byrne
[Music] [Applause] This is the venue where, as a young man, some of the music that I wrote was first performed. It was remarkably a pretty good sounding room, with all the uneven walls and all the crap everywhere. It actually sounded pretty good. This is …
The Black Hole That Kills Galaxies - Quasars
The universe looks like a vast empty ocean sprinkled with the rare islands of galaxies. But this is an illusion. Just a small fraction of all atoms are found in galaxies, while the rest is thought to be drifting in between, in the intergalactic medium. Li…
The Triumph and Tragedy of Indian Independence | Podcast | Overheard at National Geographic
So I’d like you to start out by telling me your name and your relationship to me. My name is Lata Roy Chatterjee, and I’m your stepmother. And tell us how old you are and where you were born. I’m, uh, 84 and a half years old, and I was born in Pubna, whic…
Henry Rollins: Education Will Restore A Vigorous Democracy
The way out is education. Always has been, always will be. It is the great leveler of the playing field. That’s why some politicians and some people who are of a certain bent not only fear education, they hate education. Because they realize that minoriti…