yego.me
💡 Stop wasting time. Read Youtube instead of watch. Download Chrome Extension

Worked example of a profit maximization problem | Microeconomics | Khan Academy


3m read
·Nov 11, 2024

We're told corn is used as food and as an input in the production of ethanol and alternative fuel. Assume corn is produced in a perfectly competitive market. Draw correctly labeled side-by-side graphs for the corn market and a representative corn farmer on your graphs. Show each of the following: the equilibrium price and quantity in the corn market labeled p sub m and q sub m respectively; the profit maximizing quantity of corn produced by the representative farmer earning zero economic profit labeled q sub f.

So, like always, pause this video and see if you can do this on your own before we work through it together.

All right, now let's work through it together. So we're going to do correctly labeled side-by-side graphs. So let me do this. This is going to be my horizontal axis for the market, and then this is going to be the horizontal axis for the farmer.

And this is going to be quantity in the market, quantity, quantity, and then this is going to be quantity for the farmer quantity, and then this is going to be price in the market. And whatever the market price is, that's also going to be the price that the farmer has to take because it says it's a perfectly competitive market. So the farmer is going to be a price taker here.

So let me make these axes. So this is price right over here, and this is price over here. So first, let's draw the corn market. So let me label this corn market, and we've done this multiple times already. Our demand curve might look something like this. This is our demand curve, as when price is high, low quantity demanded; when price is low, high quantity demanded.

And supply goes the other way around, so our supply curve would look something like this. And then this point, this helps us figure out this is going to be our equilibrium price, so that's p sub m, p sub m. And then this is going to be our equilibrium quantity, so q sub m.

Now this graph over here, we are going to draw the farmer. So this is going to be the farmer, the farmer's firm right over here. So the farmer is going to be a price taker, so whatever the equilibrium price in the market, that is going to be the price that the farmer is going to have to take. That market price is going to be the farmer's marginal revenue.

Now they say the profit maximizing quantity of corn produced by the farmer, by the represented farmer, earning zero economic profit labeled q sub f. We're gonna have some quantity right over here. It is the profit maximizing quantity, but it's also zero economic profit. So the zero economic profit tells us that the price must be equal to the average total cost at that quantity.

So I can make an average total cost curve that looks something like this, and I'm going to make its minimum point intersect that market price because we know from previous videos that the profit maximizing quantity happens where the marginal cost intersects the marginal revenue, which in this case would be the price that the farmer has to take from the market.

And we know that the marginal cost curve intersects the average total cost curve at this minimum point right over here. So I could draw a marginal cost curve; it might look something like this. So that is our marginal cost curve, and notice the marginal cost curve intersects the average total cost at that minimum point.

We explained that in multiple videos already, and we've explained in a previous video that the profit maximizing quantity is the quantity at which the marginal cost and the marginal revenue meet, and the price is the marginal revenue. Beyond that point, every incremental unit, the corn farmer is going to take a loss; it's going to take them more resources to produce that corn than they're going to be able to get in the market.

And we also mentioned that this has to be a situation of zero economic profit, so the average total cost has to be at that price, at that marginal revenue, right at that point. So this right over here would be our q sub f, and we're done.

More Articles

View All
NEW! Khan Academy's AI Tutor, Khanmigo - In Depth Demo
Hey everyone, Sal here, and I wanted to show you an in-depth demo of the new AI that we have happening throughout Khan Academy. What you’re going to see is that it exists in two ways. One is helping students and learners and teachers with many of the thi…
Ionic solids | Intermolecular forces and properties | AP Chemistry | Khan Academy
Let’s talk a little bit about ionic solids, which you can imagine are solids formed by ions. So let’s think a little bit about these ions. For example, we could look at group one elements here, especially things like lithium, sodium, or potassium. In many…
Artificial Intelligence - Mind Field (Ep 4)
When she said, “I love you, Harold”… Mm-hmm. What did you say back? Obviously, “I love you too.” Yeah? This is Harold. Harold and I are talking about his girlfriend, Monica. Who said it first, you or her? She said it to me. How’d it feel? It was …
Definite integrals of sin(mx) and cos(mx)
In the last video, we introduced the idea that we could represent any arbitrary periodic function by a series of weighted cosines and sines. What I’m going to start doing in this video is establishing our mathematical foundation, so it’ll be pretty straig…
Marginal utllity free response example | APⓇ Microeconomics | Khan Academy
We are told that Teresa consumes both bagels and toy cars, and they tell us that the table above shows Teresa’s marginal utility from bagels and toy cars. The first question is, what is her total utility from purchasing three toy cars? So pause this video…
Dostoevsky - Don't Become A Slave to Pleasure
In /The Brothers Karamazov/, Dostoevsky compares two different types of people: Worldly People and Monks. Worldly People are slaves to pleasure, and because of that, they lose their freedom. Meanwhile, Monks give up the pursuit of pleasure, and because of…