yego.me
💡 Stop wasting time. Read Youtube instead of watch. Download Chrome Extension

Determinants of price elasticity of demand | APⓇ Microeconomics | Khan Academy


6m read
·Nov 11, 2024

In other videos, we have already started talking about the price elasticity of demand, and what we're going to do in this video is think about the factors that might drive the price elasticity of demand in a given market to be more or less elastic. So one could say that we're going to think about the determinants of the price elasticity of demand.

Now, before we even talk about those determinants or those factors, let's just give ourselves a little bit of a review of what an elastic or an inelastic market might look like. So let me draw my price and quantity axes that we are pretty familiar with at this point: quantity on the horizontal axis, price on the vertical axis.

Remember, price elasticity of demand is the percent change in quantity for a given percent change in price. So, a high elasticity would say that you have a large percent change in quantity for a given percent change in price.

So high elasticity would look something like this; it would be a flatter demand curve. So this one might maybe look something like that. So I'll write that as high elasticity.

Low elasticity would be that your percent change in quantity does not change much, depending on your percent change in price. So a low elasticity, the closer and closer we get to a vertical curve, the lower our elasticity. So a low elasticity would look something like that: a low elasticity demand curve.

In other videos, we even think about a perfectly inelastic market, in which case you would have a vertical demand curve. But let's now think about the factors that might lead us to be closer to the high elasticity case or closer to the low elasticity case.

The factors that economists will generally point to are substitutes, time frame, income share, whether the market we're talking about is about a luxury or a necessity, and the narrowness of a market. So let's start with substitutes.

So let's imagine, first, a world where there are many substitutes for the good or service that we're talking about—many substitutes. We could think of examples in our heads for markets of goods or services where there are many substitutes.

Let's say it's the market for Fuji apples. Well, the other substitutes are the other types of apples out there—Macintosh apples and Red Delicious apples and all of those. For a given percent change in price, would you expect the percent change in quantity demanded of Fuji apples to change dramatically?

Well, if there are many substitutes, and only the Fuji apples, say, get a lot more expensive, then people will go to the substitutes. They're more likely to go to the Red Delicious or the Macintosh apples. So when you have many substitutes, that tends to lead to more elasticity.

More elasticity means that quantity, I guess you could say, would be very sensitive to price. You could go the other way around; if you have a few substitutes, well then, even if the price changes a little bit or even if it changes a lot, people say, well, I don’t know what I could substitute that with. So they might still buy a reasonably similar quantity.

So this would be less elastic.

Now, what about the time frame? How does that affect elasticity? Well, imagine that you are selling umbrellas and it is raining right now. So if we’re thinking about a short time frame while it is raining, then you could probably raise the prices on umbrellas a good bit. Assuming that you have good foot traffic, a lot of people are probably going to be willing to pay that price.

In a short time frame, things tend to be less elastic. But over a longer time frame, people might say, “Hey, you're trying to really rip me off with those umbrellas and take advantage of me! I can go someplace else and find umbrellas; I could go online or whatever else.”

In that case, people tend to be more sensitive to price. On the longer time frame, they can find their substitutes, going back to the previous determinant. So things tend to be more elastic.

Once again, you could view elasticity as how sensitive quantity is to price.

Next, income share. So let’s first think about something that makes up a very small percentage of your income, say bubble gum. Let’s say bubble gum right now is 25 cents, and if it were to go to 50 cents, that would likely reduce the quantity demanded, but it might not be so significant because going from 25 cents to 50 cents isn't going to make a big difference on most people's pocketbooks.

So, in general, the lower the income share, the lower share of income, the less elastic that market is going to be. But imagine something that is a high share of income.

So let’s say we’re talking about an automobile. If people are already spending 20 or 30 percent of their income on that automobile, and that automobile were to double the cost of that versus the gumball drop, well then people just wouldn’t even be able to demand the same quantities that they were able to before because their income just can’t support it. They have other things to spend that extra money on because their incomes just can’t support it.

So they will be highly sensitive to changes in price—high sensitivity to changes in price means more elastic.

Now, what about luxuries versus necessities? Well, let’s start with necessities. If this is something that you absolutely need, then even if the price were to go up a good bit, as long as you can still afford it, you might still go for that thing.

For example, let’s say there’s some medicine; let’s say you’re a diabetic and you need insulin. If you don’t get insulin, really bad things are going to happen. If they were to raise the price of insulin by 20, 30, or 40 dollars—assuming that you could still afford it—you would still buy the same quantity because you need that insulin.

So if something is a necessity, you’re going to be less price-sensitive. The quantity is going to be less sensitive to price, and so you’re going to be less elastic. But if something’s a luxury, if we’re talking about, you know, gold tiaras, and the price of gold were to go up dramatically, well then a lot of people say, “Well, I might not need that gold tiara anymore; it's really not going to make a big difference in my life.”

So, in general, luxuries will be associated with more elasticity.

Now, there could be exceptions. If something is in kind of the ultra-luxury category and if maybe the price were to go up, maybe the people buying it have a very low share of their income, and maybe it's a brand that at least the people buying it feel that there’s no substitute for it, well then maybe it might not be as sensitive.

But we’re talking about in broad generalities now.

The last factor that is sometimes talked about is the narrowness of the market. Now, what are we talking about there?

For example, we could be talking about the market for apples or you could talk about the market for food. Which of these markets— they're kind of both describing food— but which one is more narrow? Yes, apples are a subset of all food.

So if we're talking about the market for apples, the narrower situation tends to have more substitutes. If the price of apples goes up, people say, “Well, maybe I’m going to go buy some pears or bananas or something else instead of the apples.”

So you’re going to have more quantity, which will be more sensitive to changes in price, and so you’re going to have more elasticity.

But if you have a broader definition of your market, the market for food, well now, food looks a lot more like it’s a necessity. There are very few substitutes for food. If I stop eating food, well it’s not like I can eat, you know, change or just live off of air or whatever else. There’s really no substitutes for food; it is an absolute necessity.

So the broader the market definition, the broader the market, we tend to be dealing with less elastic demand, meaning less price elasticity of demand.

More Articles

View All
A Conversation with Aileen Lee - Moderated by Geoff Ralston
Today I am honored to have my good friend Aileen Lee here, and we’re going to have a conversation about stuff. Yeah, well, I hope we talk about like aliens. Aileen is a very public personality in the venture world, so there’s lots of great talks she has g…
Warren Buffett: A "Storm is Brewing" in the Stock Market (40% Stock Market Decline)
But I don’t mind at all under current conditions. Building the cash position, I think when I look at the alternative of what’s available in the equity markets and I look at the composition of what’s going on in the world, we find it quite attractive. War…
The Mummy's Curse | Lost Treasures of Egypt
NARRATOR: Maria has spotted the fresh tracks of a snake in the sand, and it could still be hiding somewhere in the tomb. John joins them to lend some support. Good luck. OK, if you’re still in here, I come in peace. Tapping a bit. Maria, don’t tap it, ju…
Inflection points (graphical) | AP Calculus AB | Khan Academy
We’re told let G be a differentiable function defined over the closed interval from 4 to 4. The graph of G is given right over here, given below. How many inflection points does the graph of G have? So let’s just remind ourselves what are inflection poin…
Chamath Palihapitiya: The #1 Secret to Becoming Rich
Slow and steady against hard problems. Start by turning off your social apps and giving your brain a break because then you will at least be a little bit more motivated to not be motivated by what everybody else [__] thinks about you. I saw some of the v…
Fireside Chat with Ivana Djuretic of Asher Bio
Welcome back! Next, we have a fireside chat with YC’s Jared Friedman and Ivana Dreadich. Yeah, let’s give them both a big round of applause! Ivana is the founder and founding CEO of Asher Bio. Uh, before we get started, go ahead and take a seat. But befo…