yego.me
💡 Stop wasting time. Read Youtube instead of watch. Download Chrome Extension

When there aren't gains from trade | Basic economics concepts | AP Macroeconomics | Khan Academy


4m read
·Nov 11, 2024

So let's say we're in a very simplified world where we have two countries: Country A and Country B. They're each capable of producing apples or bananas or some combination of them. What this chart tells us is if Country A put all of their energy behind apples in a day, they could produce three apples. If they put all of their energy behind bananas in a day, they could produce six bananas.

Similarly, Country B, if they put all of their energy behind apples in a day, they could produce two apples, and Country B, if they put all of their energy behind bananas in a day, they could produce four bananas.

So, given this, who has the comparative advantage in apples and who has a comparative advantage in bananas, and how should they trade? Pause this video and try to figure it out on your own.

All right, so when we're thinking about comparative advantage, we really want to think about, well, what is the opportunity cost of producing an apple in each country, and what is the opportunity cost of producing a banana in each country? Let me make another little sub-column right over here for opportunity cost.

So, what is the opportunity cost of an apple in Country A? And pause the video at any point if you get inspired. Well, to produce three apples, they would have to trade off six bananas. That means per apple, they are not producing two bananas. So this is two bananas, two bananas. I'll just write bananas per apple.

Their opportunity cost for bananas is just going to be the reciprocal of that, so 1 over 2 apples, apples per banana. And then for Country B, we can do a similar calculation, and you might be noticing something interesting is about to happen. What's Country B's opportunity cost of apples? Well, one way to think about it is if they produce two apples, that means they're giving up four bananas, or they're giving up two bananas per apple. So two bananas, bananas per apple.

Once again, if we want to think in terms of the opportunity cost of a banana, to produce four bananas, they're giving up two apples. So this is one-half of an apple per banana. I'll just write banana right over there.

So this one is a little bit interesting; they have the same opportunity cost for apples in terms of bananas, and they say have the same opportunity cost for bananas in terms of apples. And so because they have the same opportunity costs, let me write this down: same opportunity costs, there is no comparative advantage, so no comparative advantage in either.

Based on our very simple model here, there are no gains from trade. Another way we could visualize this that maybe makes it hopefully a little bit more clear. So let me make one axis here. I'm trying to draw a straight line.

All right, and then this is my other axis right over here. Let's make this one right over here, this horizontal one—let's make this the apples axis, and let's make the vertical one the bananas axis. Bananas—and we're saying per day, per day.

Of course, this is apples per day. If we look at Country A, let me do Country A in a new color. So Country A, let's say orange, if they put all of their energy behind apples, they could produce one, two—maybe spread this out a little bit—they could produce one, two, three apples in a day. If they put all of their energy behind bananas, they could produce—let's just say this is two, four, six—so that's six. This is four, this is two, this is three right over here.

Let me put markers in between to make this clear. So if they put all of their energy into bananas, they could produce six in a day, and so their production possibilities, if we assume it is a linear trade-off, would look something like this. The slope right over here would be the opportunity cost.

So the slope right over here, every time we increase apples by one, we decrease bananas by two. In this situation, we would have a slope here that is equal to—well, it's actually a negative slope. It's equal to negative two bananas, bananas per apple. So this right over here, this slope, based on how I picked the axes, is giving me the opportunity cost for apples in terms of bananas. Every time I increase an apple, how many bananas am I actually giving up? So that is my opportunity cost there.

Now, if we think about Country B—and let me do this in a new color—I'm running out of colors. Country B right over here, they can either produce four bananas or two apples or things in between. But notice it has the exact same slope. The slope is the opportunity cost, and if we switch these axes right over here, then the slope would be the opportunity cost for bananas in terms of apples.

But the big takeaway here, if you see the production possibilities of two countries and they have—and we're talking about two goods—and they have the same slope, then that means our opportunity costs are going to be the same, and there's not going to be a gain from trade.

Remember, the whole point of comparative advantage and trading is that both countries will benefit. That's really the big takeaway here. But there are situations where both countries wouldn't benefit because they have the same opportunity cost, and this was an example of one of them.

Now, the other case: sometimes they will have one that has a comparative advantage over the other. They do have different opportunity costs, and then you might have no gains from trade. Maybe there's some way that they can't know each other's opportunity cost. There's some way that they don't trade. Maybe irrespective of what the models tell us about comparative advantage, some country says, "Hey, I don't want to produce bananas. Apples are the future; that's a higher-skilled industry."

Whatever else, so there's definitely scenarios—especially even in our model, in our very simplified model—where there might not be gains from trade. The classic one, of course, is when there's no comparative advantage, and both countries have the same opportunity costs in the goods.

More Articles

View All
Inside the Extraordinary Mind of a Pinball World Champion | Short Film Showcase
[Applause] I do believe parties can take two months of planning, you know, to get them to run successfully. Yeah, good. L to be last night! So, I’ve made like um, free of cupcakes. That’s the other thing I’ve made, so I’ll bring those out kind of in ther…
How has the position of Speaker changed over time? | US Government and Civics | Khan Academy
How is the position of Speaker of the House changed over time? The position of Speaker of the House has changed a lot over time, and it has had powerful early advocates. Henry Clay, an early Speaker of the House who had three different terms as Speaker, …
Mind-Blowing Magic Magnets - Smarter Every Day 153
Hey, it’s me Destin. Welcome back to SmarterEveryDay. You might not know this, but every single hydraulic pump in every car you’ve probably ever been in has a little bitty magnet in it to catch shavings so that the mechanism doesn’t foul up. Now, I know t…
Virtually Viral | Explorers in the Field
(Gentle music) [Pardis] Early on when my research wasn’t going that well, and I was having trouble, people would be like, well, she’s in a band. But then when my research started going well, and I started publishing, they’d be like wow, and she’s in a ba…
Highest Resolution Machu Picchu Picture Ever Taken- Smarter Every Day 66
Hey, it’s me Destin. Welcome back to Smarter Every Day! So today, we’re in Peru. It’s pretty awesome. We’ve assembled a team of people, and we’re going to capture Machu Picchu in the highest resolution photo that’s ever been made of it. We’re gonna let yo…
The Neuroscience of Enlightenment, with Dr. Andrew Newberg | Big Think
When we start to think about enlightenment, we try to divide it into two basic ideas about enlightenment. And one is what I usually refer to as the small E enlightenment experiences, and these are the kind of experiences that people have a number of times…