yego.me
💡 Stop wasting time. Read Youtube instead of watch. Download Chrome Extension

Loanable funds market | Financial sector | AP Macroeconomics | Khan Academy


5m read
·Nov 11, 2024

We are used to thinking about markets for goods and services, and demand and supply of goods and services. What we're going to do in this video is broaden our sense of what a market could be for by thinking about the market for loanable funds.

Now, this might seem like a very technical term, "loanable funds," but it literally just means funds that people are supplying to be lent out to other people, and funds that people are demanding that they want to borrow. So one way to think about this market is that the suppliers in the loanable funds market are the savers.

When you go and save some money, maybe at a bank, that bank will then lend that money to someone else. Because the bank is getting interest from that person, they can also afford to pay you some interest, so you get a return. It doesn't always have to be through a bank, but that tends to be typical; it'll go through some type of intermediary.

Similarly, who are the demanders, or where is the demand coming from? I don't know if "demanders" is a real word, but I'll just write it down. So where is the demand coming from? Well, that is coming from the borrowers who are interested in maybe making an investment. Maybe some type of business opportunity is available to them.

As I mentioned, this isn't a market where the suppliers and the demanders, or the savers and the borrowers, necessarily directly interact with each other. Every now and then, you might get a loan from your sister-in-law or from your parents, but oftentimes, usually, it's going through some type of institution—some type of financial institution, usually banks—where the savers put their money in a bank hoping not just for safekeeping, but really to get a return on their money.

In order to provide a return to those savers, the bank will then lend it out to borrowers and charge interest to them. To appreciate this in the way that we've looked at markets before, I can set up two axes. In any market that we've looked at before, the horizontal axis is the quantity, and here we're talking about the quantity of loanable funds.

On the vertical axis, we normally think about the price for the good or service, but when we're dealing with loanable funds, the price is the interest rate. If we want to know the real price, we should be talking about the real interest rate.

Let's think about each of these scenarios. Let's think about the savers, who are really the suppliers in the loanable funds market. When real interest rates are lower, if real interest rates are low, they don't want to really supply a lot of quantity. They're not getting a lot of motivation to be a supplier to save in that situation.

But if real interest rates are high, well then they might say, "Hey, I'm gonna—I'm more likely to save, and I want to make my funds available for loaning out to other people." Because I get this great interest rate, especially if it's a real interest rate. So we could view it as something like this.

We could call this our supply of loanable funds. You can imagine what the demand curve for loanable funds looks like. When real interest rates are high, people say, "Hey, you know, there aren't that many business opportunities that could justify borrowing at that high of a rate," so there wouldn't be much quantity that is demanded.

But as the real interest rates—or if the real interest rates—are lower, as they get lower, then the quantity demanded of loanable funds will be higher. This is our demand for loanable funds. Like we've seen in the past, you're going to have an equilibrium quantity and price, where price in this situation is your real interest rate.

That's going to happen where these intersect. This is our equilibrium quantity, and this is our equilibrium real interest rate. Now, let's think about what would happen if one or both of these curves were to shift somehow. There are a couple of ways.

Let's start with the demand for loanable funds. There are a couple of ways that the demand for loanable funds curve could shift. Maybe, all of a sudden, people see new business opportunities—asteroid mining is becoming a thing. So people want to borrow money to get robots and send them out into space so they can mine asteroids for platinum or something.

Well, what would happen? Pause this video and think about that. Well, then at any given real interest rate, there's going to be a higher quantity demanded. So in that situation, our demand for loanable funds would shift to the right. It would look something like this.

So this is demand for loanable funds—I'll call it sub 2. Sometimes you'll see something like a prime there, but I'll call it sub 2. It has shifted to the right because of new business opportunities. Another common reason why that might shift to the right is if maybe the government is doing a lot more borrowing.

Remember, this is an aggregate market here. When the government borrows money to fuel its spending, that also has to go into the loanable funds market. So increased government borrowing would also shift this to the right.

If the opposite happened—if people thought there were fewer business opportunities, or if the government started to borrow less—well, that would shift things to the left. But let's just think about what would happen if "r," what is the current equilibrium interest rate, if that just stayed where it is. Well then, you're going to have a shortage of loanable funds, where the suppliers would be willing to supply this quantity while the borrowers are going to want this quantity here at that real interest rate.

What you're going to have happen is you're going to get to a new equilibrium point. The real interest rate is going to go up to this point—let's call that our new equilibrium real interest rate—and our quantity is going to go up as well, so Q1. In order to get more suppliers to part with their money, or at least make their money available for lending, the interest rate's going to have to go up, and we get to that point right there.

Similarly, you could have shifts in the supply of loanable funds. Let's say, for example, the savings rate changes for some reason. There's a big marketing campaign from the government or in education or in schools that say, "Hey, we need to save more for a rainy day! You need to save more for retirement."

Well then, the supply of loanable funds, if everyone saves more at any given real interest rate, could shift to the right. If the opposite happened, of course, it would shift to the left—supply of loanable funds 2.

Then what would happen? If we were at this point right over here, all of a sudden we are in a situation where there's a surplus of loanable funds at this interest rate. People are willing to supply way more loanable funds than people are demanding.

So then the price of the loanable funds—which is the real interest rate—will go down. It will go down to this new equilibrium point. So here, we could call this r sub 3, which would be our new real interest rate—equilibrium real interest rate—and this would be our new equilibrium quantity.

Actually, let me call this r sub 2 right over here. So I will leave you there. The big takeaway is that loanable funds kind of operate the way the market for most anything would, with the difference being that the price is no longer just a dollar amount; it is an interest rate. Since we want to factor out inflation, it is a real interest rate.

More Articles

View All
19-year-old dropout makes $60,000 per month online - Shopify Passive Income
Now but really quickly I want to say something to people that are watching. So okay, put this in perspective. Just think about this for a second. Nine months ago, less than a year ago, I was on my chair in my house on my computer watching this guy when he…
Vsauce Live Stream!
[Music] [Applause] [Music] Hey, Vsauce! Michael, Cameron, Jake here and we are very glad that you are here. What’s going on? Well, it’s our very first Vsauce YouTube livestream! They said it couldn’t be done, but actually, the technology has been possible…
How Dangerous is a Penny Dropped From a Skyscraper?
[Derek] What would happen if you dropped a penny off the Empire State Building? Could it kill someone walking on the sidewalk below? What does it take to create a deadly projectile? Well, I’m gonna put this to the test with original MythBuster Adam Savage…
The Car Market Bubble Just Popped
What’s up you guys, it’s Graham here. So first of all, I got to say I am shocked that more people aren’t talking about this because we’re facing a huge problem in the used car market, and honestly, it’s a disaster waiting to happen. Like, we all know tha…
Worked example: sequence recursive formula | Series | AP Calculus BC | Khan Academy
A sequence is defined recursively as follows: so a sub n is equal to a sub n minus 1 times a sub n minus 2. Or another way of thinking about it, the nth term is equal to the n minus 1 term times the n minus 2th term. With this, the zeroth term, or a sub …
Fire Syringe
So, uh, what have we got here? Oh, we’ve got something called a fire syringe. And what does it do? Oh, well, I’ll show you what it does. Some cotton wool in there. Okay, I’m just going to compress the air in it, and hopefully it will… I don’t know what it…